andrew_gelman_stats andrew_gelman_stats-2010 andrew_gelman_stats-2010-473 knowledge-graph by maker-knowledge-mining

473 andrew gelman stats-2010-12-17-Why a bonobo won’t play poker with you


meta infos for this blog

Source: html

Introduction: Sciencedaily has posted an article titled Apes Unwilling to Gamble When Odds Are Uncertain : The apes readily distinguished between the different probabilities of winning: they gambled a lot when there was a 100 percent chance, less when there was a 50 percent chance, and only rarely when there was no chance In some trials, however, the experimenter didn’t remove a lid from the bowl, so the apes couldn’t assess the likelihood of winning a banana The odds from the covered bowl were identical to those from the risky option: a 50 percent chance of getting the much sought-after banana. But apes of both species were less likely to choose this ambiguous option. Like humans, they showed “ambiguity aversion” — preferring to gamble more when they knew the odds than when they didn’t. Given some of the other differences between chimps and bonobos, Hare and Rosati had expected to find the bonobos to be more averse to ambiguity, but that didn’t turn out to be the case. Thanks to Sta


Summary: the most important sentenses genereted by tfidf model

sentIndex sentText sentNum sentScore

1 But apes of both species were less likely to choose this ambiguous option. [sent-2, score-0.909]

2 Like humans, they showed “ambiguity aversion” — preferring to gamble more when they knew the odds than when they didn’t. [sent-3, score-0.719]

3 Given some of the other differences between chimps and bonobos, Hare and Rosati had expected to find the bonobos to be more averse to ambiguity, but that didn’t turn out to be the case. [sent-4, score-0.686]


similar blogs computed by tfidf model

tfidf for this blog:

wordName wordTfidf (topN-words)

[('apes', 0.556), ('bonobos', 0.278), ('bowl', 0.278), ('odds', 0.244), ('gamble', 0.228), ('ambiguity', 0.204), ('chance', 0.189), ('percent', 0.173), ('winning', 0.145), ('chimps', 0.127), ('averse', 0.119), ('banana', 0.119), ('gambled', 0.119), ('unwilling', 0.119), ('experimenter', 0.114), ('hare', 0.114), ('preferring', 0.114), ('ambiguous', 0.104), ('aversion', 0.104), ('didn', 0.102), ('risky', 0.096), ('readily', 0.095), ('distinguished', 0.089), ('uncertain', 0.088), ('species', 0.087), ('titled', 0.086), ('humans', 0.079), ('covered', 0.078), ('remove', 0.078), ('identical', 0.076), ('assess', 0.076), ('trials', 0.074), ('rarely', 0.073), ('option', 0.071), ('thanks', 0.069), ('showed', 0.069), ('less', 0.066), ('probabilities', 0.064), ('knew', 0.064), ('turn', 0.058), ('couldn', 0.057), ('choose', 0.056), ('likelihood', 0.056), ('posted', 0.055), ('stan', 0.055), ('expected', 0.054), ('differences', 0.05), ('however', 0.043), ('link', 0.041), ('likely', 0.04)]

similar blogs list:

simIndex simValue blogId blogTitle

same-blog 1 1.0 473 andrew gelman stats-2010-12-17-Why a bonobo won’t play poker with you

Introduction: Sciencedaily has posted an article titled Apes Unwilling to Gamble When Odds Are Uncertain : The apes readily distinguished between the different probabilities of winning: they gambled a lot when there was a 100 percent chance, less when there was a 50 percent chance, and only rarely when there was no chance In some trials, however, the experimenter didn’t remove a lid from the bowl, so the apes couldn’t assess the likelihood of winning a banana The odds from the covered bowl were identical to those from the risky option: a 50 percent chance of getting the much sought-after banana. But apes of both species were less likely to choose this ambiguous option. Like humans, they showed “ambiguity aversion” — preferring to gamble more when they knew the odds than when they didn’t. Given some of the other differences between chimps and bonobos, Hare and Rosati had expected to find the bonobos to be more averse to ambiguity, but that didn’t turn out to be the case. Thanks to Sta

2 0.10339972 138 andrew gelman stats-2010-07-10-Creating a good wager based on probability estimates

Introduction: Suppose you and I agree on a probability estimate…perhaps we both agree there is a 2/3 chance Spain will beat Netherlands in tomorrow’s World Cup. In this case, we could agree on a wager: if Spain beats Netherlands, I pay you $x. If Netherlands beats Spain, you pay me $2x. It is easy to see that my expected loss (or win) is $0, and that the same is true for you. Either of us should be indifferent to taking this bet, and to which side of the bet we are on. We might make this bet just to increase our interest in watching the game, but neither of us would see a money-making opportunity here. By the way, the relationship between “odds” and the event probability — a 1/3 chance of winning turning into a bet at 2:1 odds — is that if the event probability is p, then a fair bet has odds of (1/p – 1):1. More interesting, and more relevant to many real-world situations, is the case that we disagree on the probability of an event. If we disagree on the probability, then there should be

3 0.089973733 1237 andrew gelman stats-2012-03-30-Statisticians: When We Teach, We Don’t Practice What We Preach

Introduction: My new Chance ethics column (cowritten with Eric Loken). Click through and take a look. It’s a short article and I really like it. And here’s more Chance.

4 0.087625325 1313 andrew gelman stats-2012-05-11-Question 1 of my final exam for Design and Analysis of Sample Surveys

Introduction: 1. Suppose that, in a survey of 1000 people in a state, 400 say they voted in a recent primary election. Actually, though, the voter turnout was only 30%. Give an estimate of the probability that a nonvoter will falsely state that he or she voted. (Assume that all voters honestly report that they voted.) P.S. The commenters are picking up some of the unintended “Hare and pineapple” ambiguity in my question!

5 0.079137027 1556 andrew gelman stats-2012-11-01-Recently in the sister blogs: special pre-election edition!

Introduction: 1. I can simultaneously (a) accept that Obama has a 72 percent chance of winning and (b) say the election is too close to call 2. Michael’s a Republican, Susan’s a Democrat 3. The narcissism of the narcissism of small differences 4. Obamanomics: A Counter-counterhistory 5. Not a gaffe 6. Categories influence predictions about individual consistency

6 0.075298116 942 andrew gelman stats-2011-10-04-45% hitting, 25% fielding, 25% pitching, and 100% not telling us how they did it

7 0.072686918 529 andrew gelman stats-2011-01-21-“City Opens Inquiry on Grading Practices at a Top-Scoring Bronx School”

8 0.068971008 2335 andrew gelman stats-2014-05-15-Bill Easterly vs. Jeff Sachs: What percentage of the recipients didn’t use the free malaria bed nets in Zambia?

9 0.064508446 108 andrew gelman stats-2010-06-24-Sometimes the raw numbers are better than a percentage

10 0.062432416 279 andrew gelman stats-2010-09-15-Electability and perception of electability

11 0.060807861 853 andrew gelman stats-2011-08-14-Preferential admissions for children of elite colleges

12 0.059198093 673 andrew gelman stats-2011-04-20-Upper-income people still don’t realize they’re upper-income

13 0.059058469 2076 andrew gelman stats-2013-10-24-Chasing the noise: W. Edwards Deming would be spinning in his grave

14 0.059027556 1075 andrew gelman stats-2011-12-20-This guy has a regular column at Reuters

15 0.055425633 819 andrew gelman stats-2011-07-24-Don’t idealize “risk aversion”

16 0.054948382 1079 andrew gelman stats-2011-12-23-Surveys show Americans are populist class warriors, except when they aren’t

17 0.054619752 1307 andrew gelman stats-2012-05-07-The hare, the pineapple, and Ed Wegman

18 0.054315653 582 andrew gelman stats-2011-02-20-Statisticians vs. everybody else

19 0.053026862 1115 andrew gelman stats-2012-01-12-Where are the larger-than-life athletes?

20 0.048389066 389 andrew gelman stats-2010-11-01-Why it can be rational to vote


similar blogs computed by lsi model

lsi for this blog:

topicId topicWeight

[(0, 0.051), (1, -0.015), (2, 0.019), (3, 0.013), (4, -0.004), (5, 0.004), (6, 0.017), (7, -0.024), (8, -0.014), (9, -0.044), (10, -0.024), (11, 0.004), (12, 0.004), (13, -0.02), (14, -0.004), (15, 0.016), (16, 0.021), (17, 0.023), (18, 0.017), (19, 0.025), (20, -0.012), (21, 0.03), (22, 0.015), (23, -0.005), (24, -0.001), (25, 0.0), (26, -0.015), (27, -0.005), (28, -0.023), (29, -0.03), (30, 0.001), (31, 0.021), (32, 0.023), (33, 0.008), (34, -0.015), (35, 0.008), (36, 0.039), (37, 0.007), (38, -0.003), (39, 0.004), (40, 0.012), (41, 0.015), (42, 0.016), (43, 0.001), (44, -0.001), (45, -0.004), (46, -0.008), (47, 0.043), (48, -0.029), (49, -0.018)]

similar blogs list:

simIndex simValue blogId blogTitle

same-blog 1 0.97986615 473 andrew gelman stats-2010-12-17-Why a bonobo won’t play poker with you

Introduction: Sciencedaily has posted an article titled Apes Unwilling to Gamble When Odds Are Uncertain : The apes readily distinguished between the different probabilities of winning: they gambled a lot when there was a 100 percent chance, less when there was a 50 percent chance, and only rarely when there was no chance In some trials, however, the experimenter didn’t remove a lid from the bowl, so the apes couldn’t assess the likelihood of winning a banana The odds from the covered bowl were identical to those from the risky option: a 50 percent chance of getting the much sought-after banana. But apes of both species were less likely to choose this ambiguous option. Like humans, they showed “ambiguity aversion” — preferring to gamble more when they knew the odds than when they didn’t. Given some of the other differences between chimps and bonobos, Hare and Rosati had expected to find the bonobos to be more averse to ambiguity, but that didn’t turn out to be the case. Thanks to Sta

2 0.65269184 942 andrew gelman stats-2011-10-04-45% hitting, 25% fielding, 25% pitching, and 100% not telling us how they did it

Introduction: A University of Delaware press release reports : This month, the Journal of Quantitative Analysis in Sports will feature the article “An Estimate of How Hitting, Pitching, Fielding, and Base-stealing Impact Team Winning Percentages in Baseball.” In it, University of Delaware Prof. Charles Pavitt of the Department of Communication defines the perfect “formula” for Major League Baseball (MLB) teams to use to build the ultimate winning team. Pavitt found hitting accounts for more than 45 percent of teams’ winning records, fielding for 25 percent and pitching for 25 percent. And that the impact of stolen bases is greatly overestimated. He crunched hitting, pitching, fielding and base-stealing records for every MLB team over a 48-year period from 1951-1998 with a method no other researcher has used in this area. In statistical parlance, he used a conceptual decomposition of offense and defense into its component parts and then analyzed recombinations of the parts in intuitively mea

3 0.65118277 1562 andrew gelman stats-2012-11-05-Let’s try this: Instead of saying, “The probability is 75%,” say “There’s a 25% chance I’m wrong”

Introduction: I recently wrote about the difficulty people have with probabilities, in this case the probability that Obama wins the election. If the probability is reported as 70%, people think Obama is going to win. Actually, though, it just means that Obama is predicted to get about 50.8% of the two-party vote, with an uncertainty of something like 2 percentage points. So, as I wrote, the election really is too close to call in the sense that the predicted vote margin is less than its uncertainty. But . . . when people see a number such as 70%, they tend to attribute too much certainty to it. Especially when the estimated probability has increased from, say 60%. How to get the point across? Commenter HS had what seems like a good suggestion: Say that Obama will win, but there is 25% chance (or whatever) that this prediction is wrong? Same point, just slightly different framing, but somehow, this seems far less incendiary. I like that. Somehow a stated probability of 75% sounds a

4 0.61237848 1556 andrew gelman stats-2012-11-01-Recently in the sister blogs: special pre-election edition!

Introduction: 1. I can simultaneously (a) accept that Obama has a 72 percent chance of winning and (b) say the election is too close to call 2. Michael’s a Republican, Susan’s a Democrat 3. The narcissism of the narcissism of small differences 4. Obamanomics: A Counter-counterhistory 5. Not a gaffe 6. Categories influence predictions about individual consistency

5 0.6118089 1574 andrew gelman stats-2012-11-12-How to Lie With Statistics example number 12,498,122

Introduction: This post is by Phil Price. Bill Kristol notes that “Four presidents in the last century have won more than 51 percent of the vote twice: Roosevelt, Eisenhower, Reagan and Obama”. I’m not sure why Kristol, a conservative, is promoting the idea that Obama has a mandate, but that’s up to him. I’m more interested in the remarkable bit of cherry-picking that led to this “only four presidents” statistic. There was one way in which Obama’s victory was large: he won the electoral college 332-206. That’s a thrashing. But if you want to claim that Obama has a “popular mandate” — which people seem to interpret as an overwhelming preference of The People such that the opposition is morally obligated to give way — you can’t make that argument based on the electoral college, you have to look at the popular vote. That presents you with a challenge for the 2012 election, since Obama’s 2.7-point margin in the popular vote was the 12th-smallest out of the 57 elections we’ve had. There’s a nice sor

6 0.60022748 1075 andrew gelman stats-2011-12-20-This guy has a regular column at Reuters

7 0.59964025 1540 andrew gelman stats-2012-10-18-“Intrade to the 57th power”

8 0.57857633 2335 andrew gelman stats-2014-05-15-Bill Easterly vs. Jeff Sachs: What percentage of the recipients didn’t use the free malaria bed nets in Zambia?

9 0.57724613 138 andrew gelman stats-2010-07-10-Creating a good wager based on probability estimates

10 0.57685626 1544 andrew gelman stats-2012-10-22-Is it meaningful to talk about a probability of “65.7%” that Obama will win the election?

11 0.56554055 279 andrew gelman stats-2010-09-15-Electability and perception of electability

12 0.55539221 1242 andrew gelman stats-2012-04-03-Best lottery story ever

13 0.55339968 1115 andrew gelman stats-2012-01-12-Where are the larger-than-life athletes?

14 0.54830861 628 andrew gelman stats-2011-03-25-100-year floods

15 0.54739606 1830 andrew gelman stats-2013-04-29-Giving credit where due

16 0.54455972 559 andrew gelman stats-2011-02-06-Bidding for the kickoff

17 0.54140234 29 andrew gelman stats-2010-05-12-Probability of successive wins in baseball

18 0.53794581 959 andrew gelman stats-2011-10-14-The most clueless political column ever—I think this Easterbrook dude has the journalistic equivalent of “tenure”

19 0.53503823 1237 andrew gelman stats-2012-03-30-Statisticians: When We Teach, We Don’t Practice What We Preach

20 0.53471226 108 andrew gelman stats-2010-06-24-Sometimes the raw numbers are better than a percentage


similar blogs computed by lda model

lda for this blog:

topicId topicWeight

[(2, 0.036), (6, 0.017), (9, 0.013), (13, 0.018), (16, 0.047), (24, 0.091), (35, 0.334), (36, 0.015), (53, 0.013), (72, 0.031), (77, 0.016), (80, 0.037), (83, 0.018), (96, 0.013), (99, 0.176)]

similar blogs list:

simIndex simValue blogId blogTitle

same-blog 1 0.87725377 473 andrew gelman stats-2010-12-17-Why a bonobo won’t play poker with you

Introduction: Sciencedaily has posted an article titled Apes Unwilling to Gamble When Odds Are Uncertain : The apes readily distinguished between the different probabilities of winning: they gambled a lot when there was a 100 percent chance, less when there was a 50 percent chance, and only rarely when there was no chance In some trials, however, the experimenter didn’t remove a lid from the bowl, so the apes couldn’t assess the likelihood of winning a banana The odds from the covered bowl were identical to those from the risky option: a 50 percent chance of getting the much sought-after banana. But apes of both species were less likely to choose this ambiguous option. Like humans, they showed “ambiguity aversion” — preferring to gamble more when they knew the odds than when they didn’t. Given some of the other differences between chimps and bonobos, Hare and Rosati had expected to find the bonobos to be more averse to ambiguity, but that didn’t turn out to be the case. Thanks to Sta

2 0.83848619 768 andrew gelman stats-2011-06-15-Faux-antique

Introduction: Isabella, Ava, and Chloe.

3 0.78927946 837 andrew gelman stats-2011-08-04-Is it rational to vote?

Introduction: Hear me interviewed on the topic here . P.S. The interview was fine but I don’t agree with everything on the linked website. For example, this bit: Global warming is not the first case of a widespread fear based on incomplete knowledge turned out to be false or at least greatly exaggerated. Global warming has many of the characteristics of a popular delusion, an irrational fear or cause that is embraced by millions of people because, well, it is believed by millions of people! All right, then.

4 0.78328431 881 andrew gelman stats-2011-08-30-Rickey Henderson and Peter Angelos, together again

Introduction: Today I was reminded of a riddle from junior high: Q: What do you get when you cross an elephant with peanut butter? A: Peanut butter that never forgets, or an elephant that sticks to the roof of your mouth. The occasion was a link from Tyler Cowen to a new book by Garry Kasparov and . . . Peter Thiel. Kasparov we all know about. I still remember how he pulled out a victory in the last game of his tournament with Karpov. Just amazing: he had to win the game, a draw would not be enough. Both players knew that Kasparov had to win. And he did it. A feat as impressive as Kirk Gibson’s off-the-bench game-winning home run in the 1987 Series. Peter Theil is a more obscure figure. He’s been featured a couple of times on this blog and comes across as your typical overconfident rich dude. It’s an odd combination, sort of like what you might get if Rickey Henderson and Peter Angelos were to write a book about how to reform baseball. Cowen writes, “How can I not pre-orde

5 0.72892523 942 andrew gelman stats-2011-10-04-45% hitting, 25% fielding, 25% pitching, and 100% not telling us how they did it

Introduction: A University of Delaware press release reports : This month, the Journal of Quantitative Analysis in Sports will feature the article “An Estimate of How Hitting, Pitching, Fielding, and Base-stealing Impact Team Winning Percentages in Baseball.” In it, University of Delaware Prof. Charles Pavitt of the Department of Communication defines the perfect “formula” for Major League Baseball (MLB) teams to use to build the ultimate winning team. Pavitt found hitting accounts for more than 45 percent of teams’ winning records, fielding for 25 percent and pitching for 25 percent. And that the impact of stolen bases is greatly overestimated. He crunched hitting, pitching, fielding and base-stealing records for every MLB team over a 48-year period from 1951-1998 with a method no other researcher has used in this area. In statistical parlance, he used a conceptual decomposition of offense and defense into its component parts and then analyzed recombinations of the parts in intuitively mea

6 0.70232141 1443 andrew gelman stats-2012-08-04-Bayesian Learning via Stochastic Gradient Langevin Dynamics

7 0.69794619 895 andrew gelman stats-2011-09-08-How to solve the Post Office’s problems?

8 0.69456184 80 andrew gelman stats-2010-06-11-Free online course in multilevel modeling

9 0.68897516 591 andrew gelman stats-2011-02-25-Quantitative Methods in the Social Sciences M.A.: Innovative, interdisciplinary social science research program for a data-rich world

10 0.68208057 2049 andrew gelman stats-2013-10-03-On house arrest for p-hacking

11 0.66025674 1516 andrew gelman stats-2012-09-30-Computational problems with glm etc.

12 0.65248621 296 andrew gelman stats-2010-09-26-A simple semigraphic display

13 0.64719999 1926 andrew gelman stats-2013-07-05-More plain old everyday Bayesianism

14 0.64676237 388 andrew gelman stats-2010-11-01-The placebo effect in pharma

15 0.62856483 1130 andrew gelman stats-2012-01-20-Prior beliefs about locations of decision boundaries

16 0.61215627 1264 andrew gelman stats-2012-04-14-Learning from failure

17 0.60915989 2253 andrew gelman stats-2014-03-17-On deck this week: Revisitings

18 0.59880811 2185 andrew gelman stats-2014-01-25-Xihong Lin on sparsity and density

19 0.58615845 392 andrew gelman stats-2010-11-03-Taleb + 3.5 years

20 0.56704974 2274 andrew gelman stats-2014-03-30-Adjudicating between alternative interpretations of a statistical interaction?