andrew_gelman_stats andrew_gelman_stats-2010 andrew_gelman_stats-2010-187 knowledge-graph by maker-knowledge-mining

187 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-05-Update on state size and governors’ popularity


meta infos for this blog

Source: html

Introduction: Nick Obradovich saw our graphs and regressions showing that the most popular governors tended to come from small states and suggested looking at unemployment rates. (I’d used change in per-capita income as my economic predictor, following the usual practice in political science.) Here’s the graph that got things started: And here’s what Obradovich wrote: It seems that average unemployment rate is more strongly negatively correlated with positive governor approval ratings than is population. The unemployment rate and state size is positively correlated. Anyway, when I include state unemployment rate in the regressions, it pulls the significance away from state population. I do economic data work much of the day, so when I read your post this morning and looked at your charts, state unemployment rates jumped right out at me as a potential confound. I passed this suggestion on to Hanfei, who ran some regressions: lm (popularity ~ c.log.statepop + c.unemployment)


Summary: the most important sentenses genereted by tfidf model

sentIndex sentText sentNum sentScore

1 Nick Obradovich saw our graphs and regressions showing that the most popular governors tended to come from small states and suggested looking at unemployment rates. [sent-1, score-1.218]

2 (I’d used change in per-capita income as my economic predictor, following the usual practice in political science. [sent-2, score-0.213]

3 ) Here’s the graph that got things started: And here’s what Obradovich wrote: It seems that average unemployment rate is more strongly negatively correlated with positive governor approval ratings than is population. [sent-3, score-0.869]

4 The unemployment rate and state size is positively correlated. [sent-4, score-0.718]

5 Anyway, when I include state unemployment rate in the regressions, it pulls the significance away from state population. [sent-5, score-0.869]

6 I do economic data work much of the day, so when I read your post this morning and looked at your charts, state unemployment rates jumped right out at me as a potential confound. [sent-6, score-0.904]

7 I passed this suggestion on to Hanfei, who ran some regressions: lm (popularity ~ c. [sent-7, score-0.446]

8 29 Also some other versions including lots of non-statistically-significant interactions. [sent-66, score-0.066]

9 We centered each predictor to allow easy interpretation of each main effect in the presence of interactions. [sent-72, score-0.314]

10 The punch line is that, in these models, state-level unemployment is highly predictive of lower popularity for the governor. [sent-73, score-0.751]

11 Even after controlling for these economic predictors, governors of smaller states remain more popular, but this trend is no longer statistically significant. [sent-74, score-0.899]

12 The next step is to look at other years and other statewide offices. [sent-75, score-0.1]

13 I think there are some articles on this in the political science literature that Shigeo found when we last looked at the topic. [sent-76, score-0.144]

14 In the meantime, I’ll take the position that the most popular governors tend to be from smaller states, and some of this pattern appears to be explained by economic factors. [sent-77, score-0.73]


similar blogs computed by tfidf model

tfidf for this blog:

wordName wordTfidf (topN-words)

[('unemployment', 0.371), ('popularity', 0.294), ('governors', 0.278), ('lm', 0.263), ('residual', 0.242), ('intercept', 0.235), ('obradovich', 0.234), ('sd', 0.22), ('regressions', 0.177), ('economic', 0.156), ('state', 0.142), ('popular', 0.134), ('states', 0.126), ('rate', 0.126), ('predictor', 0.122), ('smaller', 0.109), ('hanfei', 0.106), ('statewide', 0.1), ('governor', 0.09), ('pulls', 0.088), ('looked', 0.087), ('punch', 0.086), ('negatively', 0.084), ('jumped', 0.081), ('positively', 0.079), ('tended', 0.079), ('centered', 0.073), ('nick', 0.073), ('ratings', 0.072), ('approval', 0.071), ('formula', 0.07), ('presence', 0.068), ('charts', 0.068), ('morning', 0.067), ('passed', 0.067), ('versions', 0.066), ('meantime', 0.065), ('trend', 0.063), ('controlling', 0.063), ('suggestion', 0.059), ('political', 0.057), ('ran', 0.057), ('correlated', 0.055), ('remain', 0.054), ('suggested', 0.053), ('explained', 0.053), ('represent', 0.051), ('interpretation', 0.051), ('predictors', 0.05), ('longer', 0.05)]

similar blogs list:

simIndex simValue blogId blogTitle

same-blog 1 0.99999976 187 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-05-Update on state size and governors’ popularity

Introduction: Nick Obradovich saw our graphs and regressions showing that the most popular governors tended to come from small states and suggested looking at unemployment rates. (I’d used change in per-capita income as my economic predictor, following the usual practice in political science.) Here’s the graph that got things started: And here’s what Obradovich wrote: It seems that average unemployment rate is more strongly negatively correlated with positive governor approval ratings than is population. The unemployment rate and state size is positively correlated. Anyway, when I include state unemployment rate in the regressions, it pulls the significance away from state population. I do economic data work much of the day, so when I read your post this morning and looked at your charts, state unemployment rates jumped right out at me as a potential confound. I passed this suggestion on to Hanfei, who ran some regressions: lm (popularity ~ c.log.statepop + c.unemployment)

2 0.44811508 159 andrew gelman stats-2010-07-23-Popular governor, small state

Introduction: A couple years ago, upon the selection of Sarah Palin as vice-presidential nominee, I made some graphs of the popularity of governors of different-sized states: As I wrote at the time : It seems to be easier to maintain high approval in a small state. What’s going on? Some theories: in a large state, there will be more ambitious politicians on the other side, eager to knock off the incumbent governor; small states often have part-time legislatures and thus the governor is involved in less political conflict; small states (notably Alaska) tend to get more funds per capita from the federal government, and it’s easier to be popular when you can disburse more funds; large states tend to be more heterogeneous and so it’s harder to keep all the voters happy. I was curious how things have been going more recently, and Hanfei made an updated graph using data from this archive . Here’s the story: There’s lots of variation–clearly there are many other factors than state popu

3 0.16913417 323 andrew gelman stats-2010-10-06-Sociotropic Voting and the Media

Introduction: Stephen Ansolabehere, Marc Meredith, and Erik Snowberg write : The literature on economic voting notes that voters’ subjective evaluations of the overall state of the economy are correlated with vote choice, whereas personal economic experiences are not. Missing from this literature is a description of how voters acquire information about the general state of the economy, and how that information is used to form perceptions. In order to begin understanding this process, we [Ansolabehere, Meredith, and Snowberg] asked a series of questions on the 2006 ANES Pilot about respondents’ perceptions of the average price of gas and the unemployment rate in their home state. We find that questions about gas prices and unemployment show differences in the sources of information about these two economic variables. Information about unemployment rates come from media sources, and are systematically biased by partisan factors. Information about gas prices, in contrast, comes only from everyday

4 0.14096665 1985 andrew gelman stats-2013-08-16-Learning about correlations using cross-sectional and over-time comparisons between and within countries

Introduction: Antonio Rinaldi writes: Here in Italy an “hype” topic is the “staffetta tra generazioni”, handover between generations: since unemployment rate in young people is very high, someone in the government is thinking to encourage older people to anticipate their retirement to make more jobs available for youngs. I am not an economist and I don’t want to discuss the economic plausibility of such a possible measure. However, some economists deny its success simply on the basis of a correlation and regression analysis. You can see the charts used as “evidence” here: http://www.lavoce.info/per-una-vera-staffetta-generazionale/ and here: http://noisefromamerika.org/articolo/occupazione-ricambio-intergenerazionale. The first chart shows that there is no correlation between activity rate in older people and unemployment rate in younger people. The second chart shows that there is a positive linear regression (even if the author doesn’t speak of a casual relationship) between activity rate in

5 0.14092852 696 andrew gelman stats-2011-05-04-Whassup with glm()?

Introduction: We’re having problem with starting values in glm(). A very simple logistic regression with just an intercept with a very simple starting value (beta=5) blows up. Here’s the R code: > y <- rep (c(1,0),c(10,5)) > glm (y ~ 1, family=binomial(link="logit")) Call: glm(formula = y ~ 1, family = binomial(link = "logit")) Coefficients: (Intercept) 0.6931 Degrees of Freedom: 14 Total (i.e. Null); 14 Residual Null Deviance: 19.1 Residual Deviance: 19.1 AIC: 21.1 > glm (y ~ 1, family=binomial(link="logit"), start=2) Call: glm(formula = y ~ 1, family = binomial(link = "logit"), start = 2) Coefficients: (Intercept) 0.6931 Degrees of Freedom: 14 Total (i.e. Null); 14 Residual Null Deviance: 19.1 Residual Deviance: 19.1 AIC: 21.1 > glm (y ~ 1, family=binomial(link="logit"), start=5) Call: glm(formula = y ~ 1, family = binomial(link = "logit"), start = 5) Coefficients: (Intercept) 1.501e+15 Degrees of Freedom: 14 Total (i.

6 0.1347127 1524 andrew gelman stats-2012-10-07-An (impressive) increase in survival rate from 50% to 60% corresponds to an R-squared of (only) 1%. Counterintuitive, huh?

7 0.13451272 182 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-03-Nebraska never looked so appealing: anatomy of a zombie attack. Oops, I mean a recession.

8 0.13335559 1686 andrew gelman stats-2013-01-21-Finite-population Anova calculations for models with interactions

9 0.11059246 753 andrew gelman stats-2011-06-09-Allowing interaction terms to vary

10 0.10489561 649 andrew gelman stats-2011-04-05-Internal and external forecasting

11 0.10433108 1966 andrew gelman stats-2013-08-03-Uncertainty in parameter estimates using multilevel models

12 0.10371661 1388 andrew gelman stats-2012-06-22-Americans think economy isn’t so bad in their city but is crappy nationally and globally

13 0.099338084 114 andrew gelman stats-2010-06-28-More on Bayesian deduction-induction

14 0.099034384 2364 andrew gelman stats-2014-06-08-Regression and causality and variable ordering

15 0.093539238 339 andrew gelman stats-2010-10-13-Battle of the NYT opinion-page economists

16 0.091770075 383 andrew gelman stats-2010-10-31-Analyzing the entire population rather than a sample

17 0.089852996 362 andrew gelman stats-2010-10-22-A redrawing of the Red-Blue map in November 2010?

18 0.089605466 1194 andrew gelman stats-2012-03-04-Multilevel modeling even when you’re not interested in predictions for new groups

19 0.088066183 123 andrew gelman stats-2010-07-01-Truth in headlines

20 0.087066732 61 andrew gelman stats-2010-05-31-A data visualization manifesto


similar blogs computed by lsi model

lsi for this blog:

topicId topicWeight

[(0, 0.123), (1, -0.023), (2, 0.107), (3, 0.029), (4, 0.027), (5, -0.039), (6, -0.044), (7, -0.021), (8, -0.002), (9, 0.055), (10, -0.02), (11, 0.0), (12, 0.0), (13, 0.019), (14, 0.06), (15, 0.03), (16, 0.002), (17, 0.001), (18, -0.016), (19, -0.012), (20, 0.051), (21, 0.03), (22, -0.039), (23, -0.005), (24, 0.003), (25, -0.008), (26, -0.018), (27, 0.013), (28, 0.044), (29, -0.013), (30, 0.103), (31, 0.017), (32, -0.005), (33, -0.01), (34, -0.022), (35, 0.011), (36, 0.002), (37, -0.025), (38, 0.028), (39, -0.069), (40, -0.016), (41, -0.036), (42, -0.009), (43, 0.002), (44, 0.027), (45, -0.004), (46, 0.002), (47, 0.005), (48, 0.02), (49, -0.001)]

similar blogs list:

simIndex simValue blogId blogTitle

same-blog 1 0.97785842 187 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-05-Update on state size and governors’ popularity

Introduction: Nick Obradovich saw our graphs and regressions showing that the most popular governors tended to come from small states and suggested looking at unemployment rates. (I’d used change in per-capita income as my economic predictor, following the usual practice in political science.) Here’s the graph that got things started: And here’s what Obradovich wrote: It seems that average unemployment rate is more strongly negatively correlated with positive governor approval ratings than is population. The unemployment rate and state size is positively correlated. Anyway, when I include state unemployment rate in the regressions, it pulls the significance away from state population. I do economic data work much of the day, so when I read your post this morning and looked at your charts, state unemployment rates jumped right out at me as a potential confound. I passed this suggestion on to Hanfei, who ran some regressions: lm (popularity ~ c.log.statepop + c.unemployment)

2 0.8919155 159 andrew gelman stats-2010-07-23-Popular governor, small state

Introduction: A couple years ago, upon the selection of Sarah Palin as vice-presidential nominee, I made some graphs of the popularity of governors of different-sized states: As I wrote at the time : It seems to be easier to maintain high approval in a small state. What’s going on? Some theories: in a large state, there will be more ambitious politicians on the other side, eager to knock off the incumbent governor; small states often have part-time legislatures and thus the governor is involved in less political conflict; small states (notably Alaska) tend to get more funds per capita from the federal government, and it’s easier to be popular when you can disburse more funds; large states tend to be more heterogeneous and so it’s harder to keep all the voters happy. I was curious how things have been going more recently, and Hanfei made an updated graph using data from this archive . Here’s the story: There’s lots of variation–clearly there are many other factors than state popu

3 0.70817238 536 andrew gelman stats-2011-01-24-Trends in partisanship by state

Introduction: Matthew Yglesias discusses how West Virginia used to be a Democratic state but is now solidly Republican. I thought it would be helpful to expand this to look at trends since 1948 (rather than just 1988) and all 50 states (rather than just one). This would represent a bit of work, except that I already did it a couple years ago, so here it is (right-click on the image to see the whole thing): I cheated a bit to get reasonable-looking groupings, for example putting Indiana in the Border South rather than Midwest, and putting Alaska in Mountain West and Hawaii in West Coast. Also, it would help to distinguish states by color (to be able to disentangle New Jersey and Delaware, for example) but we didn’t do this because the book is mostly black and white. In any case, the picture makes it clear that there have been strong regional trends all over during the past sixty years. P.S. My graph comes from Red State Blue State so no 2008 data, but 2008 was pretty much a shift

4 0.69204938 1635 andrew gelman stats-2012-12-22-More Pinker Pinker Pinker

Introduction: After I posted this recent comment on a blog of Steven Pinker (see also here ), we had the following exchange. I’m reposting it here (with Pinker’s agreement) not because we achieved any deep insights but because I thought it useful to reveal to people that so-called experts such as us are not so clear on these issues either. AG: I noticed your article on red and blue states and had some thoughts. . . . The short summary is that I think that your idea is interesting but that, as stated, it explains too much, in that your story is based on centuries-long history but it only fits electoral patterns since the 1980s. SP: Though the exact alignment between red and blue states, political parties, and particular issues surely shift, I’d be surprised if the basic alignments between geography and the right-left divide, and the issues that cluster on each side of the divide, have radically changed over the past century. (Obviously if you define “red” and “blue” by the Republican

5 0.68620068 636 andrew gelman stats-2011-03-29-The Conservative States of America

Introduction: After noting the increasing political conservatism of people in the poorer states, Richard Florida writes : The current economic crisis only appears to have deepened conservatism’s hold on America’s states. This trend stands in sharp contrast to the Great Depression, when America embraced FDR and the New Deal. Liberalism, which is stronger in richer, better-educated, more-diverse, and, especially, more prosperous places, is shrinking across the board and has fallen behind conservatism even in its biggest strongholds. This obviously poses big challenges for liberals, the Obama administration, and the Democratic Party moving forward. But the much bigger, long-term danger is economic rather than political. This ideological state of affairs advantages the policy preferences of poorer, less innovative states over wealthier, more innovative, and productive ones. American politics is increasingly disconnected from its economic engine. And this deepening political divide has become pe

6 0.683016 1485 andrew gelman stats-2012-09-06-One reason New York isn’t as rich as it used to be: Redistribution of federal tax money to other states

7 0.67854553 1504 andrew gelman stats-2012-09-20-Could someone please lock this guy and Niall Ferguson in a room together?

8 0.67489702 1631 andrew gelman stats-2012-12-19-Steven Pinker is a psychologist who writes on politics. His theories are interesting but are framed too universally to be valid

9 0.65251303 362 andrew gelman stats-2010-10-22-A redrawing of the Red-Blue map in November 2010?

10 0.65206021 50 andrew gelman stats-2010-05-25-Looking for Sister Right

11 0.63730377 1386 andrew gelman stats-2012-06-21-Belief in hell is associated with lower crime rates

12 0.63426912 201 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-12-Are all rich people now liberals?

13 0.6191752 1985 andrew gelman stats-2013-08-16-Learning about correlations using cross-sectional and over-time comparisons between and within countries

14 0.60789502 1397 andrew gelman stats-2012-06-27-Stand Your Ground laws and homicides

15 0.60454309 2056 andrew gelman stats-2013-10-09-Mister P: What’s its secret sauce?

16 0.59615129 456 andrew gelman stats-2010-12-07-The red-state, blue-state war is happening in the upper half of the income distribution

17 0.59460717 1097 andrew gelman stats-2012-01-03-Libertarians in Space

18 0.59438658 2087 andrew gelman stats-2013-11-03-The Employment Nondiscrimination Act is overwhelmingly popular in nearly every one of the 50 states

19 0.59354693 79 andrew gelman stats-2010-06-10-What happens when the Democrats are “fighting Wall Street with one hand, unions with the other,” while the Republicans are fighting unions with two hands?

20 0.5916664 743 andrew gelman stats-2011-06-03-An argument that can’t possibly make sense


similar blogs computed by lda model

lda for this blog:

topicId topicWeight

[(2, 0.011), (6, 0.01), (7, 0.027), (16, 0.152), (20, 0.012), (24, 0.155), (32, 0.027), (43, 0.019), (52, 0.026), (58, 0.03), (82, 0.014), (84, 0.043), (86, 0.06), (90, 0.036), (99, 0.261)]

similar blogs list:

simIndex simValue blogId blogTitle

same-blog 1 0.97286147 187 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-05-Update on state size and governors’ popularity

Introduction: Nick Obradovich saw our graphs and regressions showing that the most popular governors tended to come from small states and suggested looking at unemployment rates. (I’d used change in per-capita income as my economic predictor, following the usual practice in political science.) Here’s the graph that got things started: And here’s what Obradovich wrote: It seems that average unemployment rate is more strongly negatively correlated with positive governor approval ratings than is population. The unemployment rate and state size is positively correlated. Anyway, when I include state unemployment rate in the regressions, it pulls the significance away from state population. I do economic data work much of the day, so when I read your post this morning and looked at your charts, state unemployment rates jumped right out at me as a potential confound. I passed this suggestion on to Hanfei, who ran some regressions: lm (popularity ~ c.log.statepop + c.unemployment)

2 0.9588021 1016 andrew gelman stats-2011-11-17-I got 99 comparisons but multiplicity ain’t one

Introduction: After I gave my talk at an econ seminar on Why We (Usually) Don’t Care About Multiple Comparisons, I got the following comment: One question that came up later was whether your argument is really with testing in general, rather than only with testing in multiple comparison settings. My reply: Yes, my argument is with testing in general. But it arises with particular force in multiple comparisons. With a single test, we can just say we dislike testing so we use confidence intervals or Bayesian inference instead, and it’s no problem—really more of a change in emphasis than a change in methods. But with multiple tests, the classical advice is not simply to look at type 1 error rates but more specifically to make a multiplicity adjustment, for example to make confidence intervals wider to account for multiplicity. I don’t want to do this! So here there is a real battle to fight. P.S. Here’s the article (with Jennifer and Masanao), to appear in the Journal of Research on

3 0.95501918 503 andrew gelman stats-2011-01-04-Clarity on my email policy

Introduction: I never read email before 4. That doesn’t mean I never send email before 4.

4 0.95451534 411 andrew gelman stats-2010-11-13-Ethical concerns in medical trials

Introduction: I just read this article on the treatment of medical volunteers, written by doctor and bioethicist Carl Ellliott. As a statistician who has done a small amount of consulting for pharmaceutical companies, I have a slightly different perspective. As a doctor, Elliott focuses on individual patients, whereas, as a statistician, I’ve been trained to focus on the goal of accurately estimate treatment effects. I’ll go through Elliott’s article and give my reactions. Elliott: In Miami, investigative reporters for Bloomberg Markets magazine discovered that a contract research organisation called SFBC International was testing drugs on undocumented immigrants in a rundown motel; since that report, the motel has been demolished for fire and safety violations. . . . SFBC had recently been named one of the best small businesses in America by Forbes magazine. The Holiday Inn testing facility was the largest in North America, and had been operating for nearly ten years before inspecto

5 0.94842345 1019 andrew gelman stats-2011-11-19-Validation of Software for Bayesian Models Using Posterior Quantiles

Introduction: I love this stuff : This article presents a simulation-based method designed to establish the computational correctness of software developed to fit a specific Bayesian model, capitalizing on properties of Bayesian posterior distributions. We illustrate the validation technique with two examples. The validation method is shown to find errors in software when they exist and, moreover, the validation output can be informative about the nature and location of such errors. We also compare our method with that of an earlier approach. I hope we can put it into Stan.

6 0.94583017 2179 andrew gelman stats-2014-01-20-The AAA Tranche of Subprime Science

7 0.94571042 1980 andrew gelman stats-2013-08-13-Test scores and grades predict job performance (but maybe not at Google)

8 0.94568121 1712 andrew gelman stats-2013-02-07-Philosophy and the practice of Bayesian statistics (with all the discussions!)

9 0.94552112 799 andrew gelman stats-2011-07-13-Hypothesis testing with multiple imputations

10 0.94383693 2004 andrew gelman stats-2013-09-01-Post-publication peer review: How it (sometimes) really works

11 0.94363338 1206 andrew gelman stats-2012-03-10-95% intervals that I don’t believe, because they’re from a flat prior I don’t believe

12 0.94270897 177 andrew gelman stats-2010-08-02-Reintegrating rebels into civilian life: Quasi-experimental evidence from Burundi

13 0.94257635 722 andrew gelman stats-2011-05-20-Why no Wegmania?

14 0.94219619 159 andrew gelman stats-2010-07-23-Popular governor, small state

15 0.93971539 2248 andrew gelman stats-2014-03-15-Problematic interpretations of confidence intervals

16 0.93946534 2201 andrew gelman stats-2014-02-06-Bootstrap averaging: Examples where it works and where it doesn’t work

17 0.93945992 674 andrew gelman stats-2011-04-21-Handbook of Markov Chain Monte Carlo

18 0.93929648 42 andrew gelman stats-2010-05-19-Updated solutions to Bayesian Data Analysis homeworks

19 0.93927515 481 andrew gelman stats-2010-12-22-The Jumpstart financial literacy survey and the different purposes of tests

20 0.93899411 960 andrew gelman stats-2011-10-15-The bias-variance tradeoff